Sunday, July 29, 2018

What lies ahead for Disney


On Friday, Disney and Fox shareholders approved the $71.3 merger that will transfer Fox’s 20th Century film and TV studios, a 30 percent share in Hulu, and cable networks (FX Networks, National Geographic) to Disney when the deal is completed in the first half of 2019.  Next year will be a transformative year for Disney.  In addition to this deal closing, the media giant will launch its own direct-to-consumer streaming service consisting of live action and animated movies, and end its three-year exclusive distribution agreement with Netflix.  Owning the relationship with the customer is a critical part of Disney’s [slight] pivot away from being the anchor tenet (with ESPN) in the Pay-TV bundle. 

When it terminates its agreement with Netflix, Disney loses access to over 100 million global (52+ million U.S.) subscribers and the associated licensing revenue.  Can it make these losses up with a sufficient number of its own subscribers willing to fork over $X.XX per month?  I’m not sure!  After Netflix, the largest streaming services, by number of subscribers, are Amazon, Hulu, and HBO Now.  Disney most closely resembles number four, HBO, a firm that is trying to continue to monetize a position on the pay-TV bundle while carving out a “go it alone” path.  HBO Now had only 5 million subscribers in 2017.  Disney will need a way more subscribers than that to make this new strategy work.
Top Streaming Services in 2017
Number of subscribers (millions)
Netflix
52.8
Amazon
26.0
Hulu
17.0
HBO Now
5.0
Showtime
2.5
CBS All Access
2.5
Sling TV
2.2
Starz
2.0
YouTube Red
1.5
DirecTV Now
1.0
Hulu with Live TV
0.5
PlayStation Vue
0.4
YouTube TV
0.3
fuboTV
0.1
Source: eMarketer


Saturday, July 28, 2018

ESPN is losing scale. Can it make it up in scope?


In 2010, ESPN reached its peak number of subscribers at 100 million.  In the seven years that followed, that number dropped by 12 percent to 88 million as emboldened (or fed-up) Pay-TV subscribers cut the cord.  For Disney, ESPN’s parent, the revenue loss is significant.  According to SNL Kagan, Disney was paid $7.21 per subscriber in 2016 by cable and satellite providers.  That number jumped to $9.06 if the sister networks (ESPN2, ESPNU, SEC Network) were included.  Assuming no change in programming fees, ESPN losses between $86.5 and $108.7 million in annual revenue for every 1 million decline in subscribers.  (Note: ESPN’s subscriber loss has averaged closer to 2 million per year.)

In 2017, Disney/ESPN spent approximately $7 billion on sports programming rights.  Just to cover these costs, ESPN needs 88 million subscribers paying $6.63/month.   With acceleration in Pay-TV subscriber losses expected, ESPN is going to have to get creative to sustain profitability.  It may control the bleeding somewhat by sports fans adding the newly launched direct-to-consumer app, ESPN+, that Disney is charging $4.99 per month for.  But, with this pricing model, Disney is going to have to add nearly 2 customers for every one lost by cord-cutting.  Brand reputation aside, this may be very difficult to do in an increasingly fragmented media market.     

Sunday, July 8, 2018

Zero-rating is a good for consumers, right?


“Going forward, the Federal Communications Commission will not focus on denying Americans free data.”  FCC Chairman Ajit Pai, February 3, 2017.

How can a recent court case pertaining to the credit card market inform us on whether the practice of zero-rating by internet service providers (ISPs) is good or bad for consumers?  On June 25th, in a 5-4 ruling, the Supreme Court found that the antisteering provisions in American Express’s merchant contracts were not anticompetitive in violation of Section I of the Sherman Antitrust Act.  In the Court’s majority opinion, Justice Thomas wrote that the value of a credit card network depends on the mutual interdependence of two sides —cardholders and merchants— and therefore should be treated as one market instead of two separate markets.  Specifically, if merchants were permitted to steer patrons to use alternative payment cards and, as a result, the Amex card was used less frequently, some cardholder perks would go away and interbrand competition would be reduced.

How might this concept of one market with a two-sided platform relate to the internet and the practice of zero-rating by fixed and mobile ISPs?  In its simplest form, zero-rating excludes the bytes associated with some internet traffic from counting towards the allowed monthly data amount paid for by the ISP subscriber.  The more bytes excluded the less likely the subscriber will encounter his/her data cap and have to pay the universally-disdained overage charges.  Zero-rating benefits the consumer as s/he receives more content over the network without overtly paying for it.  Moreover, to lure and retain subscribers, ISPs have upped the ante by offering more and more plans that exclude content from data caps.  In the short-run and supportive of Chairman Pai’s statement, there appears to be a net competitive benefit to those on the consumer side of the internet market. 

But, what about the other side of the platform and might what happens there impact the consumer in the long run?  To tie back to the Amex case, let’s say that the content owners and ISPs are the equivalent of the credit card companies and merchants, respectively.  What if the ISPs favor some content (e.g. HBO) over another (e.g. Comedy Central)?  Maybe it is because the content owner has tremendous brand loyalty that the ISP wants to leverage for its bottom line.  Maybe it is because the content owner can pay the additional fees to ensure its content is zero-rated?  Maybe it is because the content is owned by the ISP? 

These pricing strategies fall into the category of price discrimination, where different customers are charged different prices even though there are no differences in costs.  They are perfectly legal IF they do not harm competition (Section II of the Clayton Act).  We’ve all gone to the movies or checked into a hotel knowing that the person sitting in the seat or in the room next to us might be paying a different price than we are. The price difference could be because they are a different age, they made the reservation at a different time, or they participate in a loyalty program.  Competition is not harmed in these markets and there are some efficiency gains from the practice.  But, what about its use in content distribution over the internet?  While the FCC Chairman doesn’t want to address zero-rating and “free” data for consumers, favoritism on the content-side may eventually impact demand and what is paid on the consumer-side of the market by reducing interbrand competition.  The probability of competitive harm increases if regulators approve more vertical mergers without behavioral safeguards and give latitude to firms like AT&T to favor their own content through zero-rating schemes and other ploys.