“Going forward, the
Federal Communications Commission will not focus on denying Americans free data.” FCC Chairman Ajit Pai, February 3, 2017.
How can a recent court case pertaining to the credit card
market inform us on whether the practice of zero-rating by internet service
providers (ISPs) is good or bad for consumers?
On June 25th, in a 5-4 ruling, the Supreme Court found that
the antisteering provisions in American Express’s merchant contracts were not anticompetitive
in violation of Section I of the Sherman Antitrust Act. In the Court’s majority opinion, Justice
Thomas wrote that the value of a credit card network depends on the mutual interdependence
of two sides —cardholders and merchants— and therefore should be treated as one
market instead of two separate markets.
Specifically, if merchants were permitted to steer patrons to use
alternative payment cards and, as a result, the Amex card was used less
frequently, some cardholder perks would go away and interbrand competition
would be reduced.
How might this concept of one market with a two-sided
platform relate to the internet and the practice of zero-rating by fixed and
mobile ISPs? In its simplest form,
zero-rating excludes the bytes associated with some internet traffic from
counting towards the allowed monthly data amount paid for by the ISP subscriber. The more bytes excluded the less likely the
subscriber will encounter his/her data cap and have to pay the universally-disdained
overage charges. Zero-rating benefits
the consumer as s/he receives more content over the network without overtly paying
for it. Moreover, to lure and retain
subscribers, ISPs have upped the ante by offering more and more plans that
exclude content from data caps. In the
short-run and supportive of Chairman Pai’s statement, there appears to be a net
competitive benefit to those on the consumer side of the internet market.
But, what about the other side of the platform and might
what happens there impact the consumer in the long run? To tie back to the Amex case, let’s say that
the content owners and ISPs are the equivalent of the credit card companies and
merchants, respectively. What if the ISPs
favor some content (e.g. HBO) over another (e.g. Comedy Central)? Maybe it is because the content owner has
tremendous brand loyalty that the ISP wants to leverage for its bottom
line. Maybe it is because the content
owner can pay the additional fees to ensure its content is zero-rated? Maybe it is because the content is owned by
the ISP?
These pricing strategies fall into the category of price
discrimination, where different customers are charged different prices even
though there are no differences in costs.
They are perfectly legal IF they do not harm competition (Section II of
the Clayton Act). We’ve all gone to the
movies or checked into a hotel knowing that the person sitting in the seat or
in the room next to us might be paying a different price than we are. The price
difference could be because they are a different age, they made the reservation
at a different time, or they participate in a loyalty program. Competition is not harmed in these markets
and there are some efficiency gains from the practice. But, what about its use in content
distribution over the internet? While
the FCC Chairman doesn’t want to address zero-rating and “free” data for
consumers, favoritism on the content-side may eventually impact demand and what
is paid on the consumer-side of the market by reducing interbrand competition. The probability of competitive harm increases
if regulators approve more vertical mergers without behavioral safeguards and
give latitude to firms like AT&T to favor their own content through zero-rating
schemes and other ploys.
See: https://www.supremecourt.gov/opinions/17pdf/16-1454_new_1a72.pdf and http://transition.fcc.gov/Daily_Releases/Daily_Business/2017/db0203/DOC-343345A1.pdf
No comments:
Post a Comment